PDA

View Full Version : E.U. Feels Baltic Banking Woes



Revenant
02-23-2009, 03:42 PM
Overexposure to Central-Eastern European debt threatens Western financial solvency.

The economic situation in Central-Eastern Europe (CEE) continues to deteriorate rapidly and unpredictably. This is already affecting bank earnings, and prudent crisis management requires action and agreement for action to be made now, if major output losses and financial-sector contractions are to be avoided. This proves both a threat and an opportunity for the E.U. and its institutions.

The bulk of banking in CEE is undertaken by West European-based banks or their CEE subsidiaries. It was chronic and acute bad debt problems in home-grown banks that led to this dominance. Until recently, the benefits to CEE were obvious. Financial services were delivered by or under the supervision of experienced banks that were not amenable to the influence of local politicians, and access to international capital markets was cheaper and guaranteed.

However, 84% of West European loans from these banks to the CEE came from six countries: Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Italy and Sweden. Austrian banks' exposure is especially significant, and is equivalent to 70% of national GDP. Swedish banks' exposure is 30% of GDP, and is concentrated in the tiny Baltic economies. Risk exposure to CEE loans is concentrated in a small number of Western banks, from a handful of countries.

From the CEE viewpoint, a large proportion of its credit supply depends on a small number of geographically concentrated sources. Some 90% of the region's foreign loans come from euro-area countries; amid the present circumstances, that increases risk and thereby depresses CEE expectations.

Although there is as yet little evidence of pressure from the lending banks' parent banks or countries of origin to repatriate capital, cautious risk managers are likely counseling some reduction in exposure to mostly small and unexpectedly volatile markets, many of which have currencies that have fallen significantly against the euro.

Given the concentrated nature of CEE countries' financial services, it makes sense to have agreements in place that will cover emergencies. On the CEE side, governments will want to know that foreign-headquartered banks will not discriminate against them in a crisis. An agreement with the authorities of the foreign state in question may help, if only to provide some compensatory loans should private banks cut access to credit.

The agreements should be bilateral, and ideally formal, because Western E.U. members have so far proved incapable of coordinating either fiscal stimuli or cross-border banking crises. Where the particular bank may prove to be too large for either or both parties to save, precautionary agreements with other governments or EU institutions are needed. Such agreements may reduce the current flight of capital from CEE, which has somewhat unfairly become associated in investors' minds with the riskier emerging markets.

CEE states' positions would be much improved if the E.U. implemented the sort of coordinated fiscal stimulus they themselves dare not risk. The rush of world capital into dollar-denominated assets contrasts starkly with recent euro falls. The E.U. has a budget of barely 2% its GDP and no significant tax-raising powers. The contrast with the dollar and the U.S. could not be harsher: If the United States had a tiny, vestigial federal government, and the response to the credit crisis and recession lay with its 50 states, it is hard to imagine nervous investors choosing it as a safe haven.

This crisis threatens the euro and the euro area. Some sort of fiscal coordination is required, because, at the moment, that is the only weapon that seems to stand a chance of limiting the scale of the damage.

The crisis may offer an opportunity for the E.U.; failure to seize it will further isolate Central Eastern Europe. It is reassuring that Germany has stated that it will not allow the euro area to disintegrate, but action now might preclude the need to test that pledge.

http://www.forbes.com/2009/02/21/europe-banking-economy-business_oxford.html

SwordoftheVistula
02-24-2009, 06:15 AM
Another problem is that many of these loans are denominated in Swiss Francs, making the eastern Europeans even more likely to default as their exchange rate with the Swiss France falls:

http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/06a45f2a-0118-11de-8f6e-000077b07658.html?nclick_check=1

The crisis started in the US, but Europe is where it might turn into catastrophe.

A senior policymaker told me last week that the present situation reminded him of the 1992 crisis of Europe’s exchange rate mechanism, when one country after another became subject to speculative attacks – leading to the expulsion of the UK and Italy from the system. In a monetary union, you can no longer bet on exchange rates. But thanks to credit default swaps, you can place convenient bets on the break-up of the eurozone. Last week, speculators bet on an Irish default, and these bets make it more expensive for Ireland to refinance its debt, thus threatening to turn into a self-fulfilling prophecy.

But Ireland is not the biggest danger for the eurozone. If the country goes down, the eurozone will bail it out. Even the Germans accept this now. A far more imminent danger lurks in central and eastern Europe. The possibility of a financial collapse there is the most urgent policy issue the European Union must confront at this point. If mishandled, it could bring down the eurozone.

The crisis has hit central and eastern Europeans so disproportionately hard because of two policy errors by their governments. The first was to encourage households to obtain mortgages in foreign currencies. In Hungary, almost every mortgage is a foreign currency mortgage, mostly denominated in Swiss francs. The choice of Swiss francs is plainly ludicrous – testimony to economic illiteracy. I could just about understand foreign currency borrowings in euros, since Hungary will eventually join the eurozone. But Hungary will presumably not join the Swiss Federation. The money that Hungarian households saved on cheap Swiss interest rates has been more than wiped out by the rise in the Swiss franc.

The second policy error is directly related to the first. The new EU members treated eurozone membership as a voluntary policy choice. This is a misinterpretation of their own accession treaties. When they signed up to EU membership, they signed up to the euro as well. Only the UK and Denmark have a legal opt-out. Of course, as newly industrialised economies, they were not under an obligation to join immediately, but they were under an obligation to conduct policies consistent with eventual membership. If they had pursued such policies, they would almost all be members by now. Slovenia and Slovakia have demonstrated that, given the right policies, it was possible to enter the eurozone early on. Both these countries are now safe. For the others, the decision to procrastinate turned out to be a financial stability disaster. If confronted with a crisis such as this, you do not want to be a small open economy, on the fringes of the eurozone, with an irrelevant currency and lots of Swiss franc mortgages.

But the central and eastern Europeans got one thing right. They made sure their banks were owned by foreigners. Austrian banks are among the most active. Their exposure to eastern Europe is about 80 per cent of Austria’s gross domestic product. If Hungarian households default, it is not Hungary that will go down, but Austria. Italy and Sweden are also exposed. A central and east European crisis is therefore a systemic event for the eurozone as well. One should not therefore treat this as someone else’s problem – because it is not.

Revenant
02-24-2009, 04:40 PM
http://www.manilatimes.net/national/2009/feb/21/yehey/business/20090221bus9.html

On top of all of this. The Swiss banks sure will have their hands full.

Seems the US Govt might be trying to flush a couple more Madoffs out.